Reading time: 8 minutes

Walking around any British town or village today, it’s difficult to imagine that land might not once have been private. But this was not always the case – for centuries, landless people could access common lands and forests. There they could gather firewood, graze livestock, or grow small crops.

By Morgan WR Dunn

In a time when most people survived by subsistence farming under feudalism, the commons allowed them to eke out a little more food or warmth. While common land is no longer so common, it has a fascinating history which persists to this day.

“The Patrimony of the Poor”: Common Land in Britain

Serfs harvesting wheat in a 14th century illustration. In return for labour like this, landless Britons were given access to common, or “waste,” lands for grazing, foraging, and other subsistence activities. Wikimedia Commons.

Land was first set aside as commons in the Anglo-Saxon period, beginning in 450 CE. This was an era when early British kings were ascendant and the roots of later feudal social structures were being planted. Common lands (or “commons”) came into existence as Anglo-Saxons moved throughout England, regarding their conquered territories as prizes held in common and divided between them. 

Grazing, hunting, fishing, and gathering wood or other natural resources were shared. This system varied depending on local customs and was governed by local assemblies, or “moots”. Anglo-Saxon records mention rights of common, like “herbage,” or grazing, and “estovers,” or allowances for wood collection. 

Before technologies like crop rotation, modern irrigation, and drainage existed, each manorial house in Britain had attached to it plots of ground that were less productive than valuable farmland. Peasants, merchants, artisans, and others could access this land – land held “in common,” or for all – for their own needs. Land usage scholars have noted that, since this was a customary practice, the rights accompanying it and the rules governing it differed from place to place.

The Rights and Customs of Commoners

The first major challenge to this way of life came with the Norman Conquest in 1066. While royal forests, or areas of land (not always wooded) reserved for the use of rulers and nobles, had become an established concept under the Anglo-Saxons, King William I (“the Conqueror”) drastically expanded their size and use. The Normans introduced Forest law. Under it, anyone caught hunting, collecting wood, or even foraging on forest land would be subject to severe penalties ranging from punitive fines to death.

Pigs browsing in the New Forest, a one-time Royal Forest in southwestern England. As pigs were some of the most valuable animals English serfs and peasant farmers could afford, the right of pannage was essential to British life for centuries. Wikimedia Commons.

Norman laws seriously depleted the area available to commoners, since most people spent their entire lives living in a small geographic area and couldn’t expand elsewhere. Nevertheless, William, like the Anglo-Saxon rulers before him, allowed the landless class to use commons outside the royal reserves, as removing their ancient customary rights would have led to serious unrest and likely paralysed the early medieval economy.

These rights included that of “pasture,” or grazing livestock like cattle, sheep, and horses, although few peasants could own many, if any, such valuable animals, and the number of any animal a household could keep was restricted. Another was “estovers,” an allowance for firewood usually collected from small trees or fallen branches. Other rights included “turbary,” or cutting turf or peat for fuel, and “pannage,” setting pigs loose to forage in woodlands.

Access to common lands was always a privilege granted by whichever noble held the actual title to them. It could thus be taken away if one commoner was thought to be taking more than their share. Commons could also be “stinted” (restricted) when growing populations expanded to prevent them being ruined.

Common Land Systems Across the British Isles

England: the Open Field System

Peasants ploughing a field with oxen. Such expensive animals were largely owned by feudal aristocrats – landless families were more likely to own donkeys and geese. Wikimedia Commons.

The prevailing method of organising common land in England was the open field system. Under this arrangement, several large plots of a noble’s land were set aside for growing crops, several for hay, and some for grazing and gardening. Crops were rotated to avoid soil exhaustion. Peasants had to exchange work or rent to live on sections of the land, but this also meant they could support themselves with small crops and livestock of their own. “In the open field village,” the economist Gilbert Slater wrote, “the entirely landless labourer was scarcely to be found.”

The open field system, possibly based on the older Celtic field system, persisted for centuries, with gradual consolidation and enclosure, the restriction of land from common use, diminishing the stock over time. By the time common land effectively came to an end in England in the mid-19th century, the few remaining open field areas were in the North.

Ireland: Commonages and Clan Lands

In Ireland before the eventual English conquest, land, while administered and controlled by a lord, was owned collectively. It was divided into plots for leaders and aristocrats, but one section, the Cumhal Senorba, was set aside “for the maintenance of the poor, old, and incapable members of the clan,” and another, called “the Fearan Fine, or tribe’s quarter, was retained as the common land of the whole clan.”

This system came to an end in the aftermath of Oliver Cromwell’s conquest of Ireland. As a result of this, most of the island was confiscated by English landlords, who rented plots to peasants as in England. When late 19th century reforms did away with this arrangement, plots called commonages became the normal mode of designating Irish common land.

Scotland: Run-Rig and Other Commons

The remains of rigs, or strips of farmland, can be seen on this hillside in Drynoch, Isle of Skye. Wikimedia Commons.

Before its union with England in 1707, Scotland had a variety of types of common land. These included Crown Commons, or lands held by the king which anyone could use much like English commons, common mosses where the public could cut peat for fuel, and the run rig system. 

Under run rig, land was divided into strips called “rigs” which were rented out, often by intermediaries called tacksmen who sublet the land. Rigs would occasionally be reallocated to individual farmers, and in some areas of the Scottish Highlands they were connected to common grazing grounds open to all nearby tenants.

Enclosure: the End of the Commons

Enclosure was not met with silence by commoners. This gradual process touched off a long series of revolts and rebellions, as of the Rightboys of Ireland, part of a broader trend of public anger at the erosion of agrarian workers’ rights. Wikimedia Commons.

Commoners won a significant victory in the struggle over land rights in 1217. The Magna Carta, signed by King John in 1215, had placed substantial limits on forest law and the monarch’s rights within it. Two years later came the Charter of the Forest, which further relaxed restrictions and also enshrined pannage and agistment, the grazing of cattle specifically, in law.

But there were always those who sought to close the commons off and turn a profit from them. This process is known as enclosure. It had already appeared in the medieval period when the 1235 Statute of Merton enabled nobles to combine plots into single holdings.

Landowners sought to consolidate fields and convert communal lands into private holdings for more profitable agricultural uses. This accelerated in response to the growth of the wool trade during the Tudor era, which made pasture land for sheep extremely valuable.

Cattle grazing on Shortwood Common, Surrey in 2018. While little remains of the old common lands, traditional rights have been preserved on some and even restored on others. Wikimedia Commons.

Over time, landowners gained more and more power as traditional peasant customs lost ground and as laws transferred more and greater rights away from commoners. This trend finally culminated in the Inclosure Act 1773, which gave landowners the right to enclose land by petition with the consent of those who depended on it (this clause was often ignored) and is still in effect today. By the beginning of the 20th century, nearly 110,000 square miles had been enclosed. Today, 1.3 million acres, or just 2.1% of Britain’s total area, is common land. And while many of the rights and privileges once available to the public in these areas are long gone, many survive, perhaps most meaningfully in the form of areas of natural beauty like the Yorkshire Dales and Dartmoor in the southwest.

Articles you may also like

Tom Petrie’s reminiscences of early Queensland (dating from 1837). Recorded by his daughter – Audiobook

TOM PETRIE’S REMINISCENCES OF EARLY QUEENSLAND (DATING FROM 1837). RECORDED BY HIS DAUGHTER – AUDIOBOOK By Constance Campbell Petrie (1873 – 1926) and Thomas Petrie (1831 – 1910) Tom Petrie (1831-1910), explorer and grazier, arrived in the then convict settlement of Moreton Bay in 1837. His reminiscences of what was to become the colony of Queensland were […]

Read More
Copyright Info

The text of this article was commissioned by History Guild as part of our work to improve historical literacy. If you would like to reproduce it please get in touch via this form.